“Early in 2020, after a mysterious coronavirus
emerged out of China and then raced across the globe, a quiet new year took a
screeching turn. Stark images of ventilated patients in Italian hospital
hallways soon filled our newsfeeds. Panic erupted across the West. One after
another, governments that had been telling their citizens everything was fine
suddenly screamed at everyone to shelter in place and avoid all human contact.
It felt like the modern world had just met its Black Death.
“With no living memory of such scenes, Western
audiences reached for the timeless literature of apocalypse to make sense of it
all. But whereas ancient traditions of end times blamed spiritual causes for
the collapse of civilisations, we, being the moderns that we are, opted for
what we imagined to be a ‘scientific’ discourse – the so-called genre
of collapsology. Although some modern scholars, such as Edward Gibbon, Oswald
Spengler and Arnold Toynbee, retained essentially spiritual explanations for
civilisation decline, while embedding them in empirical ground, those who would
shape our interpretation of COVID-19 came
from a different tradition, one that took inspiration from Thomas Malthus’s
1798 thesis about the natural consequences of human development.
“Neo-Malthusians credited environmental feedback loops, not moral
failings, for regime collapse. In the 1960s and ’70s, works by Paul Ehrlich and
Donella Meadows et al argued that the world’s population was growing so fast it
would soon outstrip resource supplies, leading to (among other things)
widespread food shortages. More recently, Jared Diamond wrote of the role that
environmental depletion and diseases played in the fall of civilisations, and
his theory that the collapse of Easter Island resulted from overexploitation of
the natural environment has enjoyed particular resonance. For its part, the COVID-19 pandemic
revived old theories about the role that diseases played in regime collapse,
and we were reminded that plagues had laid low the Roman Empire and
destroyed European feudalism.
“Except, that wasn’t what happened. At least, not quite the way
supposed.
“The thesis that environmental stresses cause regime
collapse remains a topic of great debate. We can start just with the cases
mentioned above. The alarmist warnings in the 1970s about overpopulation soon
gave way not to concerns about food shortages, but about the problems caused by
global overproduction of food, which was driving down food prices and
accelerating the urbanisation of the developing world. Regarding Diamond’s book
about Easter Island, pretty much from the get-go it faced strong criticism for
its questionable evidence. For similar reasons, many historians of the Roman
Empire doubt that
the plague played a part in its downfall. As for the Black Death, in much of
Europe it didn’t end feudalism but actually reinforced it.
More generally, measured by the scale of the loss in human life as a proportion
of the total population in the affected areas, 19th-century epidemics of
cholera, and the flu pandemic of 1918, all took a far greater toll in
the Western world than COVID-19.
Yet you’d be hard-pressed to find hints of regime stress in response to any of
them.
“Still, the scholars who make a case for the civilisational impact
of epidemics might be on to something. For starters, the link between empires
and disease is quite strong, with cholera, tuberculosis, syphilis, bubonic
plague, smallpox and other diseases all fanning out across the
trade routes of empire. Tellingly, when one contrasts the responses to the COVID-19 pandemic
of, say, China and Western countries, it seems plausible that this pandemic could
hasten the relative decline, if not the fall, of the West. But given that China
and the West confronted the same plague, why have the outcomes differed so
wildly? Fortunately, history offers some insights.
An
exogenous shock must encounter a vulnerability to bring down a regime
“Let’s return to the Black Death of 14th-century Europe. The
thesis that the plague ended feudalism starts with the fact that Europe’s
labour supply dropped suddenly and sharply. This then augmented the bargaining
power of the labouring classes, altering their relations to the nobility. But
as mentioned, in much of Europe, and particularly in the east, the nobility
responded by then reinforcing feudal bonds. However, in other places, the legal
system permitted the renegotiation of the relationship between lords and
producers. For example, in England, the evolution of Common Law had created a
framework that made it possible for land tenure to change from feudal to
market-based relations. As a result, when the Black Death caused an agrarian
crisis, English society produced new forms of tenancy, thereby accelerating the
decline of feudalism. In effect, English feudalism had a vulnerability to
exogenous shock that was not present in other parts of Europe.
“As it happens, the thesis that an exogenous shock must encounter
a vulnerability to bring down a regime happens to fit the case of the Roman
Empire. Recent historiography attributes that
empire’s fall not to plagues but to the Hunnish invasions. Importantly, though,
the sudden incursion of the Huns didn’t itself signal the Roman Empire’s
collapse. The Huns emerge into the historical record in the 4th century, but
it would be another century before they toppled the empire – which is to say,
the exogenous shock alone didn’t change anything. Until well into the 5th century, the
Romans dealt with the Huns as they had always done with frontier invaders,
using a combination of repression and negotiation to neutralise the threat. But
in the mid-5th
century, at around the time of the empire’s greatest
economic output, its reckless expansionism multiplied the conflicts on its
borders, such that it could no longer concentrate its firepower on one foe.
Thus, the vulnerability did not result from Rome’s internal weakening, as the
Gibbon thesis had maintained. It actually came at the point when the empire was
at its peak in both economic output and, it would appear, hubris.
“That an empire’s strength might actually be its weakness,
creating vulnerabilities to exogenous shocks that didn’t exist in earlier
stages of its history, bears consideration in light of the comparatively poor
performance of Western countries in dealing with the COVID-19 pandemic.
Even more importantly, it could help us chart the
likely long-term geopolitical impacts of the pandemic. While far more
devastating in human lives, the 1918 flu pandemic did little economic harm to
Western societies. In contrast, COVID-19 plunged
today’s West into an economic slump that will set back growth, in some cases by
years, hastening its decline relative to China and much of the erstwhile global
periphery. All told, the same exogenous shock, a very different outcome: COVID-19 seems
to have found a vulnerability that did not exist in the West in 1918 – and does
not exist in much of the Western world’s former periphery.
“When the COVID-19 pandemic hit and
countries went into lockdown, markets crashed. To keep their markets and
economies afloat, Western governments began raining cash, borrowing trillions
of dollars and adding an average fifth of gross domestic product to national
debts. The result was dramatic. Instead of the feared New Great Depression,
Western economies by and large experienced short recessions, followed by sharp
rebounds. Markets, meanwhile, scaled unprecedented heights. The economic
firepower of the Western world was shown to be seemingly limitless. When
contrasted with the relatively modest expense incurred by governments in
response to the 1918 flu pandemic, observers noted how much more Western
countries could now do than before. Richer than ever, and with deep pools of
capital, governments enjoyed the luxury of being able to spend heavily to
protect their citizens and preserve their economies.
“But if that appears to be a sign of strength, it might also reveal
a weakness. Consider an analogy. I once had a conversation with an Irish
colleague in which I marvelled at how, in the space of little more than a
generation, Ireland had transformed from a poor country into a rich one.
‘Correction,’ he said, ‘we’re a high-income country, we’re not yet rich,’ going
on to explain that it would take many more generations to actually accumulate
the wealth in endowments, investment funds and the like that characterise rich
countries. And the thing about wealth is that, when you have it, you have to
keep spending to preserve it. Suppose, for example, that one year you earned $1 million. You
could spend it, enjoying the high life, but running the risk alluded to by my
colleague – that, if in the next year you lost your job or business, you’d be
back down to zero. So instead, you could invest it, say, by building a house.
That way you’d have capital you could live off if hard times returned. But
you’d also have incurred other expenses – repair bills, utility charges,
property taxes, decorating costs, and the need to buy and replace furnishings.
“Empires also entail ongoing costs. The richer an empire becomes,
the more it must spend to preserve that wealth. As the Roman Empire expanded
into virgin lands, it built up the massive estates that enabled it to
accumulate its endowment of capital, much of which survives to this day in
roads, ruins and aqueducts. But those lands were virgin only to the Romans.
Other people already lived there, and as they were beaten back or enslaved by
the Romans, resistance to the empire inevitably grew. Rebellions were thus a
constant feature of frontier life. That created the need for a standing
military and the tax revenues to sustain it.
“For most of the history of its empire, Rome was able to
concentrate military forces on comparatively disorganised and weak opponents
and, coupled with diplomatic measures such as subsidies, thereby neutralise the
threats. However, as the empire grew richer, not only did it make more enemies,
but those enemies had the capacity to more effectively withstand Roman assaults
because they’d been increasingly exposed to Roman military and administrative
technologies, and had accumulated wealth from trading across the imperial
frontier (the Vindolanda tablets revealed just how much of a frontier
garrison’s food was sourced from across the frontier). The very wealth of the
empire was what had produced this vulnerability.
Today’s
immigration bolsters Western capital, plugging the labour shortages that are
emerging
“The modern West shows a similar arc. At the time of the 1918
pandemic, most of the world outside Europe and its then ‘white dominions’
(Canada, Australia, New Zealand) and the former colonies of the United States
were either colonies of one of the European empires, notionally independent but
in an economically subservient status (China, Latin America), or struggling to
resist Western assimilation (Japan, the Ottoman Empire). Nationalism was
embryonic in the Asian and African colonies, but it would be the 1930s, and
especially during the Second World War, before it began to significantly
challenge European dominance. In terms of its share of global output, the West
was still rising, its peak to come only after the war when the US used a set of
institutions (NATO, the World Bank and IMF, the United Nations) to effectively
unify Western countries into a confederal empire – a model not unlike that used
in the late Roman Empire, in fact. The flow of capital in the world economy
came from the global periphery to the West. Firms in New York, London, Paris
and other Western cities banked the surpluses. Meanwhile, the population of the
Western world was young and growing, meaning that the vast majority of its
people were either in or about to enter the workforce. In short, the West was still ascendant, and
busily accumulating its wealth.
“At the turn of the millennium, the West (developed OECD
countries) accounted for four-fifths of global economic output. Since then,
with the erstwhile periphery of the global economy rapidly rising as the net
flow of capital shifted in its favour for the first time, that share has been
declining, suggesting that the highwater mark reached 20 years ago
was in fact the peak of the West. Some contemporary commentators, recalling
that the wealth of the peak Roman Empire attracted the barbarian invasions,
warn that we face a similar fate today if we don’t act urgently. Spotting the
foe among immigrants from the global periphery, Right-wing politicians who want
to close the borders find support from scholars such as Niall Ferguson, who, in
accounting for Islamist terrorism in Western countries, has written that
immigrants today resemble the invaders of Rome in that they ‘have coveted
[Europe’s] wealth without renouncing their ancestral faith … Like the Roman
Empire in the early 5th
century, Europe has allowed its defences to crumble.’ This,
he says, ‘is exactly how civilisations fall’. It sounds reasonable but it’s not
true.
“Invasion was the proximate cause of one civilisation’s fall, not
the underlying cause. To begin with, the argument that modern immigration amounts
to an exogenous shock is feeble at best. The invasions that toppled Rome were
large-scale military assaults organised by external actors. Today, aside from a
very small share of illegal immigration, the influx is fragmented and managed
almost entirely by the importing state. If you doubt how extensive that state’s
control is, spend a day with an undocumented immigrant. More importantly, the
invasions of antiquity seized capital, especially when the invaders obtained
land and any loot they could find. Today’s immigration actually bolsters
Western capital, plugging the labour shortages that are emerging amid ageing
populations.
“The more significant analogy is to the vulnerability to exogenous
shock that comes from having accumulated so much wealth. The location of that
vulnerability today is entirely different, though. Over the previous
generation, as economic growth has slowed in Western countries, wealth has
started growing faster than income. And whereas wealth once depended on income,
now for much of the population income depends on wealth. This is especially
true for the share of the population that is retired, which in Western
societies averages around a fifth. Since a drop in wealth entails a loss of
income for wealth-holders, that gives the state a very strong incentive to
preserve the value of that wealth. This incentive is further strengthened by
the fact that the retired share of the population tends to be the most engaged
in politics (illustrating Machiavelli’s rule
that today’s losers constitute a more formidable political constituency than
tomorrow’s winners).
“What threatens that wealth, which is held largely in real estate
and pension funds, is not a foreign invasion whose purpose is to seize those
assets, as happened to Rome. For all the talk of fearmongering and xenophobia,
we would have to be facing something like organised raids by undocumented
immigrants hacking into share-registries and appropriating the assets of
pension funds for Ferguson’s analogy to be remotely apt. Nor for that matter is
the threat a disease outbreak that reduces the agricultural income of land, as
was the case for Europe’s medieval nobility. The coronavirus pandemic ravaged
Western people and societies but, as has been much discussed, the performance
of stock markets
has continued to be great for owners. Nevertheless, in the response of markets
to the year’s events, there might be a clue to the vulnerability of the West,
one that COVID-19 helped
to expose and possibly exacerbate.
“Consider the difference between market crashes today
and those of history. When in 1929 the stock market collapsed, the Great
Depression followed. Then, after the massive government wartime spending that
John Maynard Keynes himself said was the first major successful experiment with
fiscal stimulus, the economy took off. But it wouldn’t be until the 1950s that
the stock market returned to the levels it had reached in 1929.
“In contrast, over the past 30 years or so, Western
countries have used a different set of tools when addressing market crashes, be
they in stocks, bonds or real estate. They have pumped monetary stimulus
directly into asset markets, and have targeted fiscal stimulus less at
protecting incomes than at preserving asset values by, for example, bailing out
banks or providing tax breaks for property purchases. After all, governments
had committed themselves to the neoliberal dogma of fiscal prudence and were,
if anything, cutting spending. So, while the economy has chugged along
sluggishly, asset markets have repeatedly bounced right back. Those two
outcomes might not be unrelated to one another. By inflating asset values,
monetary stimulus amid fiscal austerity raises fixed costs and steers
investment away from productive activities, thereby inhibiting economic growth.
In other words, whereas government stimulus programmes once kickstarted
economic growth, today they tend to protect accumulated wealth. Western
societies spend a lot of money just to stay rich.
COVID-19 did
not topple the West. But it might have hobbled it in its competition with the
global South
“The massive fiscal and monetary response to the COVID-19 pandemic
looks no different. When Western economies were forced into lockdown, their
governments borrowed some $17
trillion in order to keep businesses and consumers afloat,
and to shore up asset values. For now, the size of the tab doesn’t overly
concern economists. Western countries have carried higher debt loads in the
past and, with interest rates expected to remain ultra-low for years, the cost
of servicing the debt remains very manageable. The problem, rather, is what the
debt is used for.
“Returning to the analogy of the million-dollar year and the house
you built with it, the difference between fiscal stimulus then and fiscal
stimulus now is arguably the difference between taking out a loan to add a
sundeck or swimming pool to the house, and taking out a loan to repair flood
damage. The first will augment the house’s value, the second merely preserves
it. Last year’s massive stimulus was not designed for a new era of economic
growth. It was heavily oriented towards just keeping businesses and the economy
afloat. But the risk is that, by bailing out many firms that added little
dynamism to the economy, Western countries will lock in a Japanification of the
economy, a syndrome that first emerged after Japan’s 1989 crash, characterised
by chronic anemic economic growth. In the global periphery, debt-fueled
investment tends to increase output and productivity more than is the case in
Western countries, where much borrowing is essentially geared to keeping us in
the lifestyles to which we’ve grown accustomed. The odds are therefore good
that the response to the pandemic will only reinforce the long-term trend, of
future growth being increasingly skewed towards the periphery. COVID-19 did
not topple the West. But it might have hobbled it in its competition with the
rising economies of the global South, most of which were once colonies of, or
subservient regimes to, Western countries.
“The wealth of the Roman imperial economy lay in land. Owned by
the 10th of society that comprised the nobility, its revenues were taxed to
support the military, whose job it was to protect the asset from outsiders. The
wealth of today’s Western economy lies in financial markets, and is owned mostly by
the top 10th of society that belong to the global 1 per cent. A wider group
than one might suppose, since it includes almost any homeowner with a defined
benefit pension, this is effectively the modern nobility. Although it faces
no threat from invasion, the cost to society of preserving it in its current
state might be getting as onerous as that of the late Roman Empire.” (Aeon).
John
Rapley is a political economist at the University of Cambridge, as
well as a senior fellow at the Johannesburg Institute for Advanced Study. His
latest book is Twilight of
the Money Gods: Economics as a Religion and How it all Went Wrong (2017).
He lives in London and Johannesburg.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.